The tension between "popularism" as an electoral strategy and a democratic one π June 13, 2021
What is popular with a true majority of people is not always electorally feasible in a system with counter-majoritarian electoral institutions.
This is my weekly data-driven newsletter on politics, polling, and democracy β and whatever else Iβm thinking about. If you want more frequent posts on these subjects please sign up forΒ a paid subscription. I send out subscribers-only posts twice each week.
Some historians trace political populism to Ancient Rome. The populares (Latin for βfavoring the peopleβ), a political faction that existed at the time of the Republic and included figures such as Tiberius and Gaius Gracchus, Publius Clodius Pulcher (no, not that Publius), Julius Caesar, and Augustus, pushed for reforms to make life easier for normal plebeian Romans β and usually at the expense of Romeβs ruling-class patricians. (Of course, the fuller story is not so black and white. Many popularis consuls and tribunes were patricians themselves, and often used the βfriend of the peopleβ label just to consolidate power.)
One could also posit that so long as there have been societies, there have been hierarchies; and so long as there have been hierarchies, there have been people struggling for equity, and champions of their interests. In Ancient Athens, where democracy flourished before crumbling internally and being ultimately stamped out by external armies, representation came originally at the expense of the upper echelons of the ruling class (though full political membership was never actually extended to the poorest residents, not to mention slaves).
When I think of some wings of the modern progressive movement, I always end up coming back to the populares. They have in their likeness a group of progressives now calling themselves βpopularistsβ who argue that left-leaning politicians should emphasize the popular parts of their platform β like wealth redistribution, social spending, and progressive tax structures β and distance themselves from unpopular aspectsΒ β like abolishing the police or highlighting race in campaign messages (or so the argument goes). The most recognized faces in this faction might be David Shor, the progressive data scientist who is having a bit of a prolonged moment in the media spotlight, and Sean McElwee, the founder of the left-leaning think tank Data for Progress.
Journalist Lisa Lerer has a profile of McElweeβs company in the Times this week. There is a good bit of editorial puffery in the piece β I am not sure the group really deserves credit for recent sci-tech funding bills or for getting Deb Haaland nominated asΒ the first Native American cabinet secretary, as Lerer implies β but some quotes sound pretty, well, popular β in the majoritarian sense. To quote at length:
For Data for Progress, the strategy is Politics 101: Politicians like policies that are popular.
βThe secret sauce here is that weβve developed a currency that theyβre interested in,β says Sean McElwee, the executive director of the group. βWe get access to a lot of offices because everyone wants to learn about the numbers.β
The big βsecretβ? Polling data thatβs targeted, cheap andΒ fairly accurate.
Aides to Democratic congressional leaders say Data for Progress can quickly poll on policies β like expanding theΒ Child Care Tax CreditΒ orΒ unemployment benefits, or spendingΒ $400 billion on senior careΒ β that would be considered too specific for a full survey by some other polling firms. And by finding ways to do operations that pollsters traditionally outsource, the organization can charge tens of thousands of dollars less than more established firms, according to Mr. McElwee.
Data for Progress then uses those quick-turnaround surveys to push its version of a progressive agenda, boosting liberal candidates in primaries and persuading Democrats to rally around popular liberal policies once in office.
One note is: of course theyβre doing this β itβs basic politics. Every progressive group is trying to do the same thing. Thatβs not to knock the strategy, but the missed story here is in how Data for Progress has been more progressive than other groups (if, indeed, they have been β success here is hard to quantify). Maybe theyβve been able to do this because they have shied away from endorsing more unpopular progressive policies, a choice that has drawn them fire from the left. Or maybe they have mastered social media circulation for their reports. Maybe itβs a combination of both!
But what I find really interesting is in analyzing where the βdo popular things!β strategy matches what youβd expect from a majoritarian political movement, and where it doesnβt. To quote Lerer at length again:
βThe point of being a progressive and being involved in politics is to make progress happen,β said NoiseCat, an activist and author who was Data for Progressβs first employee. βAt a certain point progress should mean we got x and y thing done that made peopleβs lives better. I think itβs kind of ironic that a lot of progressives forget that the main point is weβre supposed to do the progress thing.β
Over the past three years, Mr. McElwee made his own shift from self-described βOverton Window moverβ to a more pragmatic approach, coming to embrace Mr. Biden β βI donβt like him very much,βΒ he said in 2019Β beforeΒ meeting with his campaign less than a year laterΒ β and moving away from calls to #AbolishICE, a slogan he helped popularize that became a rallying call for the left in 2018. (Only about a quarter of voters backed the ideaΒ of eliminating Immigration and Customs Enforcement, according to polling at the time.)
Now, his group advocates what Mr. McElwee has called a βnormie progressive theory of change,β backing liberal candidates who can build broad coalitions around popular policies. Think lawmakers like Representative Lauren Underwood, who flipped her suburban Illinois district, rather than more firebrand progressive leaders like Representative Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez.
On policy, theyβve come to embrace what they believe are the most popular parts of a liberal agenda as a way of persuading voters who might be skeptical of bolder rhetoric. Emphasizing a clean electric standard, instead of a carbon tax, for example. Or focusing on passing Mr. Bidenβs agenda through reconciliation rather than fighting over abolishing the filibuster, a proposal that currently lacks sufficient support among Senate Democrats.
β¦ βWeβre relatively young, but my belief about progressive politics is that first and foremost we have a moral obligation to win,β Mr. McElwee said. βThe demands in a lot of corners for policymakers to hold positions that are highly unpopular is wrong.β
Of course, what is popular is not always right, and what is unpopular is sometimes good. I donβt think McElwee or NoiseCat would disagree! But their case for progressivism dovetails with a lot of the majoritarianism that seeps into the literature on public opinion polling and American, democracy, and that got me thinkingβ¦
One big challenge for the progressive electoral case for doing popular things is that it is definitionally different from doing popular things for the sake of majoritarian representative democracy. Thatβs partly because our electoral system is biased towards Republicans, as a feature of both the House and Senate punishing voters who live in cities. So the effective electoral majority of voters is different from the majority of all voters, or even all Americans β who we might think have more domain to decide the general will of the nation.
The progressive βpopularismβ is also different from majoritarian βpopularismβ because the voters who live in marginal states or districts are demographically different and have different issue attitudes and policy preferences. So the progressive βdo popular thingsβ is often a re-stylization of βdo things that a coalition of politically engaged non-whites, educated whites and non-college whites can tolerate.β That might lead you to adopt a different set of policies, and a different politics, than you would if we had higher-turnout elections or a more proportionally representative electoral system.1
Now, I admit that this is all fine if your goal is to win elections and pass good, progressive policies. But if youβve adopted a more inclusive definition of public opinion, our modern populares still leave a lot to be desired. That is ultimately the fault of our framers, and I support the general direction the likes of McElwee and Shor are taking things (with some other disagreements on data and narrative-building), but the shortcomings of electoral popularism are nevertheless real.
Posts for subscribers
June 10: Polls show non-voters, not Trump voters, make up the largest share of vaccine-reluctant Americans. Luckily, they are also particularly responsive to monetary incentives to get shots
June 12: A thread for subscribers on global views of the US recovering from their Trump-era lows.
Links to what Iβm reading and writing
I regret that I have no reading recommendations for you this week. I have been too busy writing for work and finishing the first round of edits of my book to really dive into anything substantial. I will have more to link for you next week.
Email me
Thatβs it for this week. Thanks so much for reading. If you have any feedback, please send it to me at this address β or respond directly to this email. I love to talk with readers and am very responsive to your messages.
If you want more content, you can sign up forΒ subscribers-onlyΒ posts below. Iβll send you one or two extra articles each week, and you get access to a weekly gated thread for subscribers. As a reminder, I have cheaper subscriptions for students.
In the meantime,Β follow me on Twitter for related musings.
βDo popular things!β might also lead you to ignore policies that are currently unpopular but could be made popular through the political process, but we can leave that for another time. Making this point in a parenthetical distracts from the flow of the argument.